Photo by Kelli McClintock on Unsplash https://bit.ly/3LkJmFY

Amid the talk about tax changes set to cut the middle-income rate to 30%, a shortage of workers and incomes not keeping up with the cost of living, one common threat shines through.

It’s the cost of childcare, which, according to new calculations, imposes an effective tax as high as 70% on a second-earner wanting to work a fourth or fifth day a week.

The example in this chart is for a family on average male and female wages with two children under five, whose mother is considering working an extra day.



Such a mother with two children needing childcare would lose 32% of her first day’s wage in reduced family tax benefits, and a further 11% in childcare fees (net of subsidy) amounting to an effective marginal tax of 43%.

On her second day she would also pay tax (earning above the tax free threshold), and on her third day would lose 47% of her earnings, made up of 23% in tax and 24% in extra net childcare fees.

If she worked a fourth day, this would jump to 67% of that day’s earnings, made up of 36% in tax and 31% in extra net childcare fees.

If she worked a fifth day, the impost would climb to 70% of that day’s earnings, made up of 35% in tax and 35% in extra net childcare fees.

The 67% and 70% effective marginal tax rates are severe, and beyond what we would normally consider to be a reasonable take from a day’s pay packet.

More women could be working

In the past few months the proportion of working-age Australian women in paid work has climbed to a record high of 60%, but it remains well below that in some of the countries to which we normally compare ourselves, including New Zealand in which 64.2% of working-age women are in paid work.

If Australia’s rate of female employment was lifted to New Zealand’s, an extra 460,000 Australian women would be in paid work.

Employed women in Australia are more likely to work part time than employed women in any other member of the 38-nation OECD apart from Japan, Switzerland and the Netherlands.

It’s childcare that holds women back

Asked why they are unable to work more hours, almost half the women surveyed by the Australian Bureau of Statistics nominate “caring for children”.

Asked to nominate the incentive that would do the most to help them work more hours, half pick “access to childcare”.

The high cost of childcare steers women away from full-time work toward the role of primary caregiver at home. This in turn limits their career progression, their economic security, their retirement savings and their ability to afford housing.

It is also likely to limit fertility, which has fallen to 1.6, well below replacement levels, and limits tax revenue and Australia’s access to skills.

Employers are crying out for workers

Job vacancies are at a record high with employers crying out for skilled workers.

An analysis prepared for Chief Executive Women found that if women’s employment reached that of men’s, an extra one million full-time equivalent workers would become available, 800,000 of them with diplomas or more.

Separate modelling prepared for the National Foundation for Australian Women finds that expanding the provision of childcare (including by lifting the wages of childcare workers) would boost Australia’s labour supply 2%.

After ten years it would boost gross domestic product 1.6%.

Minor progress

In response to sustained calls for reform, the government last year boosted the childcare subsidy for families with two or more children in childcare, and removed the annual subsidy cap.

While addressing some of the most egregious effective marginal tax rates, these changes have not brought down the high costs for workers on average wages.

Labor and the Greens have promised to cut childcare costs. The so-called teal independents are also campaigning on the issue.

To work, such policies will need to be backed by an investment in the pipeline of childcare workers.The Conversation

 

This article is republished from The Conversation under a Creative Commons license. Read the original article.

This article has 3 comments

  1. Wouldn’t a more neutral tax policy approach be to allow tax deductions for childcare and leave it to taxpayers as to their choices?

  2. Miranda Stewart

    Thanks for the comment. The problem with that option is that it benefits the top 20% of the population the most, and far more than the bottom 80%. It would need to be combined with public provision of care or subsidies/grants to remainder of the population anyway to achieve universality. It is also fiscally costly, and would need to be capped to stop ‘gold plating’. While it is targeted at individuals – which I like – all of these problems mean that I favour universal public provision or payment for childcare to achieve gender equality and workforce/early child education goals.

  3. But why is it equitable to tax a family on one income where the wife likes staying at home and looking after her own children in order to subsidise a higher income woman with a golden child married to another high income earner? It seems there is gender inequity in that the single income family pays and gets nothing, is taxed without regard to the number of people living on that income and without regard to the wife’s preferences. There are actually families where women (and their men) like children and from a social and economic point of view they do the country a service by raising its future citizens. Adam Smith had some good comments in the Theory of Moral Sentiments about educating children in the home versus institutional care.

Leave a comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

*